Habit Persistence and Keeping Up with the Joneses: Evidence from Micro Data Enrichetta Ravina? New York University November 2005 Abstract This paper provides evidence that habit persistence is an important determinant of household consumption choices, in a setting that allows for heterogeneity and household-specificinterest rates. By estimating Euler equations for a representative sample of U.S. credit-card account holders, I find that the strength of external habit, captured by the fraction of the consumption of the reference group that enters the utility function, is 0.290, and that the strength of internal habit, represented by household past consumption, is 0.503. My results are robust to the inclusion of various measures of economic activity in the regression, tests for the presence of aggregate shocks, liquidity constraints, precautionary saving motives, and learning. Aggregation of the Euler equations as a weighted average of individual marginal rates of substitution accounts for heterogeneity and market incompleteness and preserves the results. ? I would like to thank Debbie Lucas, Kent Daniel, Bill Rogerson and Paola Sapienza for long discussions, support and guidance. Special thanks go to Donald P. Jacobs and the U.S. credit card company that provided the data. I am also grateful to Roc Armenter, Paco Buera, Francesco Caselli, John Campbell, Janice Eberly, Martin Eichenbaum, Mike Fishman, Joel Hasbrouck, Johannes Horner, Ming Hsu, Arvind Krishnamurthy, David Laibson, Ron Laschever, Martin Lettau, Annamaria Lusardi, Stefan Nagel, John Panzar, Marcin Peski, Karl Schmedders, Christopher Polk, Matthew Rabin, Marciano Siniscalchi, Mark Seasholes, Costis Skiadas, Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, partecipants at the Russell Sage Foundation Behavioral Camp 2004, and seminar participants at Kellogg School of Management (Fi- nance), Northwestern University, Cornell, NYU-Stern, Harvard Business School NOM and Finance groups, Brandeis, UNC at Chapell Hill, London Business School, Stockholm School of Economics, the FED Board of Governors, the Western Finance Association 2005 Meeting, the Society of Economic Dynamics 2005 Meeting, the 2005 Econometric Society World Congress, and the NYU Stern Macro Lunch for valuable discussions and suggestions. Financial support from the Northwestern University Dissertation Year Fellowship, Banca d?Italia and Fondazione Einaudi is gratefully acknowledged. All remaining errors are mine. Comments are welcome: eravina@stern.nyu.edu. The ideas of habit formation and social comparisons in consumption choices have a long history in economics, dating back to Thorstein Veblen?s 1899 "The Theory of the Leisure Class," and James Duesenberry?s 1949 "Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior". These studies, and the many studies written thereafter, postulate that individuals derive utility not only from the level of their current consumption, but also from how their consumption compares to their own past consumption (internal habit) and the consumption of the people around them ("Keeping Up with the Joneses," or external habit). Habit formation models have proven very successful in providing theoretical explanations of a variety of dynamic asset pricing phenomena and macroeconomic facts. In the asset pricing litera- ture, they have been employed to explain the equity premium puzzle (Constantinides (1990), Abel (1990, 1999), Campbell and Cochrane (1999)), the procyclical variation of stock prices (Campbell and Shiller (1988)), and the countercyclical variation of stock market volatility (Harvey (1989)). In the macroeconomics literature, habit persistence frameworks explain business cycle facts (Boldrin, Christiano and Fisher (2001)), the equity home bias (Shore and White (2002)), savings and growth (Carroll, Overland and Weil (2000)), and consumption?s response to monetary and other shocks (Fuhrer (2000)). However, despite these models? impressive track record in simulations with aggre- gate data, there is only mixed evidence on whether they reflect actual preferences. The empirical studies that have addressed this question so far have mostly followed the macroeconomists? approach to aggregate consumption, leaving the micro foundations of the phenomenon largely unexplored. In this paper, I look into actual household consumption decisions and estimate a log-linearized Euler equation for a representative sample of U.S. credit-card holders. The estimation equation incorporates internal and external habit motives, using a setting characterized by uninsurable income shocks and household-specific interest rates. My empirical strategy builds on the many studies that examine micro-level consumption and shows two novel features. First, I exploit the detailed information on the evolution of household financial variables. I use this information to build a more powerful instrument set, and to directly control for the e? ect of household-specific interest rates, debt burden, and credit availability. These controls are valuable in disentangling the e? ect of internal habit from that of liquidity constraints. They also have the advantage of allowing me to estimate the reaction of consumption to household- specific interest rates, rather than the risk-free rate most of the previous literature has had to use. Second, I define and test a more intuitive measure of the external reference point of each household (HH), the consumption level of the city in which the household lives, measured by city-level sales, 1 rather than the consumption of the entire nation, as in previous studies. To address the potential endogeneity of city-level consumption in the Euler equation, in addition to using an instrumental variables approach that exploits lagged information, I show that my results are robust to using an alternative, strictly exogenous measure of changes in the external reference point, whether somebody in the city of the household wins the lottery. To measure consumption, I use a novel panel data set, the Credit Card Panel (CCP), which consists of 2,674 U.S. credit-card accounts located in California, for the period between the third quarter of 1999 and the third quarter of 2002. I construct the consumption measure as the sum of all the credit-card purchases over the quarter for the households that are active credit-card users. My comparisons with the U.S. Census and the Survey of Consumer Finances show that my sample is representative of the U.S. population for both demographic characteristics and borrowing behavior. Moreover, this variable exhibits the characteristics we expect to see in household consumption: a hump-shapedpathoverthelifecycle,andanincreasingrelationshipwithincome. Althoughit is far from perfect, this measure of consumption allows me to overcome some of the drawbacks of previously used data sets, such as the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), which contains only information on food consumed both at home and at restaurants, and the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX), which provides a very detailed measure of consumption, but only follows households up to five quarters, and does not contain any household-specific geographic or detailed financial information. I find that the strength of external habit, captured by the consumption of the reference group, is 0.29 (significant at the 5% level), and that the strength of internal habit, represented by household past consumption, is 0.503 (significant at the 1% level). These coe? cients represent the fraction of city-level aggregate consumption (or household?s own past consumption) that enters the util- ity function as the reference level to which the household compares itself. A coe? cient of zero would imply that a household is not influenced by the consumption of its neighbors (its own past consumption), and the model would then collapse to the standard one used in the literature. On the contrary, a coe? cient of one would mean that the household only cares about the way its consumption compares to the neighbors? (its past own consumption), and not about the absolute level. These findings provide micro evidence that supports the theories that explain macroeconomic and asset pricing phenomena by introducing habit persistence in the utility function. The magni- tude of the coe? cients is in line with the conclusions of these theories, and points to a large e? ect 2 of habit formation. Iconfirm my findings by using a battery of robustness checks. To control for the possibility that city and lagged household-level consumption growth capture the e? ect of some omitted variable, I repeat the estimations adding to the regression the change in city-level unemployment rate, current and future state-wide income growth rates, and measures of city housing market conditions. I also use lottery winnings to measure the change in external reference points. To address the concern that unobservable aggregate shocks might influence the results, I add time dummies to the regression and repeat the estimation separately for each major occupation in the data set to address the concern that such shocks might a? ect di? erent HHs in a di? erent way. I also directly test for the presence of aggregate shocks following the methods in Runkle (1991), and I detect no aggregate shock. These results reduce the concern that aggregate shocks influence the findings. All the tests confirm the economic and statistical significance of the habit persistence coe? cients. Alternative explanations of the findings include the presence of liquidity constraints, precau- tionary saving motives, and learning about the household?s income profile. These phenomena, like internal habit formation, cause consumption to adjust slowly to changes in income, and therefore in- duce a positive correlation between current and lagged consumption growth rates. Following Zeldes (1989), I test the habit formation hypothesis against a liquidity constraintsmodelbyre-estimating the Euler equation on two subsamples of unconstrained and credit-constrained HHs. I perform further tests by including the lagged growth rate of income and a credit constrained indicator into the regression. The tests show some evidence of liquidity constraints in addition to those accounted for by the household-specific borrowing rate, but indicate that these liquidity constraints are not the cause of the results. The precautionary motive and learning stories have similar implications. I test them further by adding a measure of consumption uncertainty to the regression. Again, the tests confirm the validity of the habit persistence interpretation of the evidence. The results di? er from those in Dynan (2000), who investigates internal habit formation in annual food consumption using the PSID and reaches negative conclusions. A comparison of the two methodologies indicates that the main reason for these discrepancies is the instrument set used in this study, due to the availability of household-specific financial information. I find that once I drop the financial variables from the instrument set I cannot capture the endogenous variables as well as before and, most important, that the internal habit coe? cient drops from 0.60 to 0.13. Finally, I examine the aggregate implications of the micro findings. Following Attanasio and Weber (1993b) and Brav, Constantinides and Geczy (2002), I estimate an Euler equation on ag- 3 gregate data, which I obtain by taking the weighted average of HHs? marginal rates of substitution (MRS). This procedure takes into account that due to market incompleteness and liquidity con- straints, at any point in time the MRS of di? erent HHs are not necessarily the same. I find a habit persistence coe? cient of 0.515 (significant at the 5% level). On the contrary, an econometrician who uses the same data to calculate the MRS of a representative agent that consumes per capita consumption will find no evidence of habit persistence. The paper is organized as follows. Section 1 contains a brief overview of the related literature. Section 2 describes the data and compares them to those traditionally used in the literature. Section 3 presents the Euler equation that guides the estimation, describes my empirical strategy, and illustrates the results. Section 4 contains various robustness checks, and Section 5 examines alternative explanations for the results. Section 6 examines the aggregate implications of my micro findings. Section 8 concludes. An appendix, available upon request, contains detailed information on my sample selection, the features of the data and the model. 1 Related Literature This paper is related to three main strands of literature: the empirical asset-pricing studies that investigate habit formation using a representative agent framework; the micro-consumption liter- ature, from which I borrow the estimation techniques and the focus on the micro data; and the many studies that examine the e? ect of social influences on happiness and economic choices. The papers belonging to the first category vary in the instruments used, the horizon analyzed and the specifics of the estimation equation. These papers reach mixed conclusions. Eichenbaum, Hansen, and Singleton (1988) find evidence of habit persistence in leisure choices, but not in consumption, while Heaton (1995) finds evidence of durability at very short horizons and of habit persistence at quarterly frequencies. Conversely, Constantinides and Ferson (1991) find support for habit formation in monthly, quarterly and annual data. More recently, Chen and Ludvigson (2003) finds support for a non-linear form of internal habit. My paper di? ers from these studies in that it does not use the abstraction of the representative agent, with all the necessary assumptions related to market completeness and the types of heterogeneity that such an abstraction involves. Instead, I test the micro story behind habit formation models. I also analyze the aggregate implications of the findings from a "micro perspective," which takes into account the e? ect of market incompleteness and liquidity constraints. 4 My study is related to the micro consumption literature, such as Attanasio and Weber (1995), and the literature surveyed in Deaton (1992) and Browning and Lusardi (1996), for the estimation techniques. Within this area of study, my paper also provides new evidence on the importance of accounting for liquidity constraints in the analysis of household consumption decisions. Thus, my research is related to the papers of Hayashi (1985a) and Zeldes (1989), and to studies of liquidity constraints. I also analyze the sensitivity of consumption choices to household-specific interest rates, and find that, contrary to the conclusions reached previously from the analysis of the risk-free rate, households do respond to prices. Work in this area includes papers by Attanasio and Weber (1993a and 1995), Ausubel (1999), Gross and Souleles (2002), and Vissing-Jorgensen (2002). Finally, my paper also builds on Attanasio and Weber (1993b) in my analysis of the aggregate implications of the micro findings. At the intersection of these two areas of study there are a few papers that investigate the implications of habit formation at the micro level. In addition to Dynan (2000), the other such studies are Lupton (2003) and Brunnermeier and Nagel (2005). Rather than directly examining consumption, these papers look at the implications of habit formation for households? stock market investment. In particular, Lupton (2003) estimates a proxy for the habit level and shows that, consistent with the theory, the habit level is negatively related to the share of the household portfolio that is invested in stocks. On the contrary, Brunnermeier and Nagel (2005) analyze the link between idiosyncratic wealth changes and portfolio allocations and conclude against habit persistence. Besides the literature on household-level consumption, asset pricing and macroeconomics, my paper is related to the literature that studies the implications of interpersonal e? ects and time nonseparabilities in settings that range from status and conformity (Dupor and Liu (2003), Frank (2005)), happiness (Luttmer (2005)); criminal behavior and welfare choices (Case and Katz (1991), Bertrand, Luttmer and Mullainathan (2000)); auto purchases (Grinblatt, Kelohariu and Ikaheimo (2004)), and stock market participation (Hong, Kubik and Stein (2004)). Among these studies, the closest work to mine is that of Luttmer (2005) who, using various measures of happiness, illustrates how people care about relative positions and feel worse o? when others around them earn more. This result is consistent with the finding in my paper that households care about "keeping up with the Joneses". 5 2DataDescription To measure household consumption, I use the CCP panel data set, which comprises 2,674 U.S. credit-card accounts located in California, for the period between the third quarter of 1999 and the third quarter of 2002. The data provide information on spending and borrowing patterns, the evolution of interest rates, and credit availability. The data also give a snapshot of the main economic and demographic characteristics of the account holder and the zip code of the area in which he or she lives.1 To measure the external reference point, I link these data to city-level quarterly retail sales data. To perform robustness checks I conflate the data to Census, BLS and ACCRA city-level information on median house values and rent, median income, unemployment, price-level data, and mortgage rates. Table I describe the definition and sources of the variables. I present summary statistics in Table II. In constructing the sample, to obtain a more meaningful measure of consumption I exclude people whose accounts are inactive and those who seldom use their credit cards. Following earlier studies, I also exclude retired account holders, because modeling their consumption and borrowing decisions is very complex and requires the consideration of issues such as bequests, failing health and other factors that are not specific to the scope of this study. Section A of Appendix I provides a detailed description of the sample selection procedure. 2.1 Demographic and Financial Characteristics The Credit Card Panel (CCP) is representative of the U.S. population in terms of both demographic characteristics and borrowing behavior. Section B of Appendix I compares the demographics of the account holders to those of the U.S. population reported in the 2000 U.S. Census. The Appendix shows that the distributions of income and age are very alike. The main discrepancy is due to the fact that HHs in the lower income range, and individuals who are either very young or old, are under-represented in the credit-card data set. The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), which is the main source of information for assets and liabilities of U.S. households, also shares this feature, because people in those age categories are less likely to own financial instruments. Finally, my data set contains information on the occupation of the account holders. However, I note that it is harder to make a comparison with the Census Bureau figures, given the di? erent classification criteria. My data set also compares well with the U.S. data on household borrowing behavior. The 1 One of the major U.S. credit card issuers, which wishes to remain anonymous, provided the data set. 6 sample is similar to the SCF on the percentage of people who do not pay their credit-card balance in full at the end of the month. The SCF estimates this percentage at 44.4%. In my sample it is 45.75%. However, studies such as those by Laibson et al. (2000) and Gross and Souleles (2002) show that the SCF survey su? ers from under-reporting of debt. One of the specific advantages of my data set is that it is not a survey. Therefore under-reporting and measurement error in the financial variables are not an issue. Comparisons with a large multi-issuer credit card data set covering the period between 1995 and 1998 and used by Gross and Souleles (2002) further confirms that the CCP correctly represents the level of indebtedness and interest rates faced by the households. 2.2 Credit Card Expenditures as a Measure of Consumption I measure household consumption as the sum of the purchases and cash advances charged on the credit card each quarter. I note that my data set contains information on the size and timing of balance transfers, and that I exclude these quantities from the consumption measure. Because this sample is representative of the U.S. credit-card accounts, an important question is whether credit-card expenditures are a good measure of household consumption. Panels A and B of Figure I show that this measure of consumption exhibits the characteristics we expect to see in household consumption, a hump-shaped path over the life cycle and an increasing relation with income. Credit-card purchases represent an increasing fraction of U.S. consumer spending. Roughly 24% of people purchases in the United States are made by credit cards, retail cards, and debit cards. Statistics from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) and other sources indicate that in the year 2000, the average American had five or six credit cards and used them to charge over $1 trillion in purchases, more than he or she spent in cash.2 While these statistics provide support for using credit-card spending as a measure of consumption, they also raise the issue of whether having information about one credit card is enough. To address this issue, I build quarterly nondurables and services expenditures from the CEX, following the criteria in Attanasio and Weber (1995). Using CEX data, I estimate the amount that the average household spends on credit cards is between $1,143 and $1,212. In comparison, the average credit-card expenditure in my sample is approximately $700, which shows that the HHs in my data set make heavy use of this credit card and therefore provide a good measure of their expenditures. Section C of the Appendix provides 2 Lim, Paul J., and Matthew Benjamin. "Digging Your Way Out of Debt", U.S. News and World Report, (3/19/01); Gerdes and Walton (2002) and Zinman (2004). 7 details on this calculations. The main advantage of my data in comparison to the PSID is that they provide a more com- prehensive measure of consumption than food consumed at home or at restaurants, which has been proven inadequate for many reasons.3 The CEX negates some of the drawbacks of the PSID by providing a very detailed measure of overall consumption. However, the CEX only interviews fam- ilies for up to five quarters, and the survey does not contain any household-specific geographic or detailed financial information. Onefeatureofthesedataisthatwecanobserveexpendituresfluctuate on this card even though they stay relatively stable overall, if the appeal of using this card versus another varies over time. Information on interest rates and credit line variations, unused portion of the credit line and balance transfers in and out of the card and time dummies helps to control for such e? ects. Finally, I note that, despite I don?t have information on the fraction of credit-card purchases related to durables goods, the presence of goods would bias the results against finding the positive coe? cient implied by internal habit. Table III compares the mean and standard deviation of my consumption measure to those of both micro-level and aggregate data, and shows that these measures are comparable. The statistics confirm that household consumption is very noisy, with a standard deviation of 2.73 if I use all the observations down to 0.37 if, like Zeldes (1989), I consider only those cases in which the growth rate of consumption is between -1.1 and 1.1. I also provide a comparison with the CEX data. Since these are cross sectional averages, I build the same quantity in my data set. The volatility of my individual consumption measure is 0.33, compared to 0.06 obtained by Brav et al. (2002) for the 1982-1996 period. I note that the assumption underlying my estimation is the separability between credit-card expenditures and the rest of the consumption basket. Macroeconomic models of cash and credit goods can shed light on the issue of separability. 3 First, food is a necessity, its share of expenditure falls with wealth, and it might not represent well the overall consumption basket. Moreover, using food as a proxy for total consumption implicitly assumes separability between food and other commodities, and this has been rejected by numerous studies. In particular, Attanasio and Weber (1995) analyze the bias induced by using PSID food consumption rather than a more general measure and find it sizeable. Another problem with the PSID measure of consumption is that the way the question about food expenditure is posed leaves a lot of space to the interpretation of the timing of the variable making the choice of the correct timing for the instrumental variables very hard. Finally, Runkle (1991) estimates that up to 76% of the variability of food expenditure is noise. 8 2.3 City-level Consumption As the reference group of the household I use the city in which the household is located. My measure of the consumption of the reference group is city-level quarterly per capita taxable sales, which I obtain from the California Board of Equalization (BOE). I use this variable because it is a very comprehensive, natural measure of city-level consumption and it is a good aggregate equivalent to credit card expenditures. The main categories it excludes are necessities (such as food consumed at home, prescription medicines, etc.) and sales of goods intended for resale. Also, retail sales constitute an important component of personal consumption expenditures at the national level. The National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) constructs this quantity from a variety of sources, among which a monthly sample of national retail sales plays a central role. The measure I use here is not a sample, but the total of all reported taxable sales. Therefore, it is not influenced by sampling procedures and errors. Table IV presents a comparison of the summary statistics of aggregate consumption constructed with city-level sales data and personal consumption expenditures on nondurables and services from NIPA. The two measures compare very well in their variability and are highly correlated. The main di? erence between them is due to the fact that NIPA includes housing services. 3 Estimation and Empirical Evidence on the Micro Foundations of Habit Persistence Households face uninsurable income shocks and borrowing rates that depend on their asset position and credit history. Davis, Kubler and Willen (2004) show that disregarding borrowing frictions, and especially the wedge between borrowing and lending rates, can lead to unrealistic predictions in terms of the amounts borrowed and the portfolio allocations of the households. Despite this evidence and due to lack of data, empirical analyses of consumption decisions usually assume that HHs can borrow and save at the same rate. In this paper I depart from these assumptions. In Appendix II, I present a standard model of intertemporal choice that incorporates uninsurable income risk and household-specific borrowing rates. The Euler equation I derive from this model guides my choice of the variables to consider in the empirical analysis and o? ers a framework for interpreting the results: u ci,t = ?E t h [u ci,t +1 + ?? E Y u hi,t +2](1 + (R fi,t +1 ? 1)1[Y Hi,t +1])(1 + (R Ci,t ? 1)1[B ]) ? ?u hi,t +1 i (3.1) 9 where 1[Y Ht +1] is an indicator function that equals one for high realizations of income that will allow theHHtorepaythecreditcardinfullnextperiod.1[B ] is an indicator function that equals one if the HH has an unpaid balance in the current period. These results are intuitive. The household decides how much to consume today versus tomorrow by weighting future utility and di? erent interest rates against the probability that it will actually face them. If we disregard for a moment the e? ect of the habit stock, we can see that if the HH consumes $1 less today it loses u c (c t ) and gains the following: in the next period the HH?s credit- card balance will be $1 lower, making one more dollar available for consumption, and yielding autilityofu c (c t +1). In addition to this gain, if the income realization is high enough that the HH is able to repay the balance in full, the HH will earn the gross risk-free rate on the dollar moved through time and the utility will be u c (c t +1)R ft +1. If the HH carries a balance, consuming one dollar less today means that the credit-card balance next period will be R Ct dollars less. The utility deriving from this intertemporal transfer will be u c (c t +1)R Ct if the HH does not have enough resources to pay the balance in full in period t+1,andu c (c t +1)R Ct R ft +1 if it does and can invest the dollar charged on the credit card at the risk-free rate. The presence of the habit stock generates an additional e? ect because when the HH consumes one dollar less today it increases tomorrow?s utility not only directly, but also indirectly by decreasing its habit level. I note that HH income does not enter the Euler equation, since HHs optimize the consumption path and o? set predicted changes in income with asset transactions, while unanticipated changes in income are reflected in the error term. This result does not hold for those HHs that are liquidity constrained. A big advantage of the data set is that I can take the degree of liquidity constraints into account in my empirical analysis. My assumptions about HHs? expectations on the evolution of income that are consistent with (3.1). These assumptions are flexible, and include income processes following ARMA models and both trend and di? erence stationary income processes. 3.1 Specification and Estimation Strategy Following Deaton (1992), I can express equation (3.1) as a second-order di? erence equation in u ci,t . The solution is given by: u ci,t = ?E t h u ci,t +1(1 + (R fi,t +1 ? 1)1[Y Hi,t +1])(1 + (R Ci,t ? 1)1[B ]) i (3.2) 10 Equation (3.2) holds approximately if the number of lags of consumption entering the habit stock is small relative to the HH lifetime horizon, and if the HH has static expectations about future interest rates. The equation holds exactly if the interest rates are constant. Following the consumption literature, I consider a log-linear version of (3.2): lnu ci,t =ln? + k +lnu ci,t +1 +ln(1+(R fi,t +1 ? 1)1[Y Hi,t +1]) + ln(1 + (R Ci,t ? 1)1[B ]) + ? i,t +1 (3.3) where ? i,t +1 contains an expectation error, a multiplicative measurement error in consumption and preference shocks, and k contains second and possibly higher moments of the variables. As is traditional in the literature, I assume that these variables are either constant or uncorrelated with the instruments used in the estimation. The utility function depends not only on the level of current consumption, but also on own past consumption, the consumption of the reference group and demographic characteristics: u (c i,t ,H i,t , ? i, h i,t )=u (c i,t ? h i,t ? H i,t )exp(? 0? i,t ) (3.4) The variable h i,t represents the internal habit stock and depends on the household?s past con- sumption: h i,t = ?c i,t ? 1 In this framework, to maintain the marginal utility constant, an increase in past consumption must be followed by an increase in present consumption, because the habit stock to which con- sumption is compared is higher. Therefore the HH will try to smooth not only consumption levels, but also changes. The HH?s consumption will react slowly to changes in permanent income to avoid the risk of building a habit too quickly. Theoretical papers usually model internal habit formation by including a large number of consumption lags in the utility function. However, empirical inves- tigations are usually limited to one lag as adding extra ones would require very long lags of the instruments to insure exogeneity. The variable H i,t represents the external habit level. I model it as a function of the consumption 11 ofthecityinwhichtheHHlives: H i,t = ? 0C i,t + ? ? 1C i,t ? 1 (3.5) ? i,t represents household demographic characteristics. Attanasio and Weber (1993 and 1995) show that age, family characteristics and labor supply choices are very important explanatory fac- tors for individual consumption. I condition on the optimal value of these variables by incorporating them into the utility function in the multiplicative way shown in (3.4): ? i,t = ? 1ag e i,t + ? 2ag e 2i,t + a i + t t + e i,t (3.6) where a i is an unobservable HH-specifice? ect, t t is a time-varying e? ectthatisconstantacross HHs, and e i,t an idiosyncratic component orthogonal to the previous two. I also add to some of the estimations individual characteristics such as the marital status of the HH?s head, homeownership, income bracket, occupation and, in some specifications, the median income, house value and unemployment rate in the zip code area of the HH at the end of 1999. To control for cyclical fluctuations in consumption, I include seasonal dummies in the estimation. This specification is equivalent to modeling the discount factor as dependent on HH socioeconomic characteristics and the time and seasonal dummies. I can rewrite the log-linear Euler equation (3.3) more extensively as: ? ln c i,t = k 1 + ? 0? ln C i,t + ? ? 1? lnC i,t ? 1 + ? ? lnc i,t ? 1 + ? ln(1 + (R fi,t ? 1)Pr[Y Hi,t ]) +? ln(1 + (R Ci,t ? 1 ? 1)1[B ]) + ? 1? ag e i,t + ? 2? ag e 2i,t + Seas.Dummies + ? i,t (3.7) where, following Muellbauer (1988) and Dynan (2000), I approximate the expression ln u (c i,t ? H i,t ? h i,t ) with lnu (c i,t ) ? ln u (H i,t ) ? lnu (h i,t ).4 For simplicity and flexibility, I specify the utility function to depend linearly on the growth rate of HH and aggregate consumption. This specification subsumes, among other factors, the isoelastic functional form widely used in the literature. Since this equation reflects the fundamental dynamics of habit persistence, the results of the estimation do not constitute only a test of the specific model presented, but also of the general idea of habit formation. I also note that the estimation takes into account unobserved household heterogeneity in consumption levels, since the equation is in first di? erences and the HH fixed e? ect a i contained 4 Muellbauer (1988) and Dynan (2000) show that the correlation between this approximation and the exact ex- pression is higher than 0.90 for reasonable values of the coe? cients. 12 in (3.3) drops out. The estimation strategy exploits the panel aspect of the data set and the wide cross-sectional variation in the external reference point faced by households living in di? erent cities. I estimate the equation by using a GMM procedure with robust standard errors. I treat as endogenous both household and city-level consumption and the interest rates either because they are simultaneous or uncertain at the time the HH makes the consumption decision, or because they are a? ected by measurement error. The instruments I use in the estimation are the second lag of the marginal tax rate, the city-level unemployment rate, inflation rate, mortgage rate, the state-level disposable income growth rate, and some individual variables such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged o? , automatic credit line changes, and a credit constrained indicator. The macroeconomic literature shows that aggregate and city-level indicators of economic activity are good predictors of the risk-free rate and city-level consumption growth. The individual variables capture the house- hold lagged asset position and resources on hand. Table V shows that the autocorrelation in HH consumption growth rates is negative and consistent with a MA(1) structure that is induced by the presence of measurement error and taste shocks when true consumption changes are not serially correlated.5 Therefore, I choose not to use past lags of the consumption growth rate as an instru- ment. The basic assumption required for identification is that the instruments are uncorrelated with the preference shocks, measurement error and expectation errors contained in ? i,t . I test this assumption by performing various tests of overidentifying restrictions, such as the Hansen J test for the entire instrument set and the di? erence-in-Sargan statistic on the subset of household-specific instruments. Both tests support the validity of the instruments set. Finally, the standard errors are robust to arbitrary correlation and heteroskedasticity within households. However, once the time dummies account for a common aggregate component, I assume that the errors are uncorrelated across households. 3.2 Empirical Evidence Table VI reports the main results of my estimation of (3.7). I regress the household consumption growth on past HH consumption growth, as a measure of internal habit stock, city-level per-capita consumption and its first lag, as a measure of the external habit level, the household-specific interest rate, HH demographic characteristics and seasonal dummies. Column I of Table VI estimates 5 Similar values of the autocorrelation coe? cients are obtained by Hayashi (1985b), who analyzes a panel of Japanese household expenditures. 13 the basic model, and columns II to IV progressively add to the specification family composition, home ownership and occupation. I correct the standard errors for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. I also include controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies in all the regressions. All versions of the estimates are consistent with the presence of habit formation in household consumption decisions. The specification reported in column IV of Table VI shows that after con- trolling for own consumption and demographic and socioeconomic characteristics, the e? ect of the external habit is significant at the 5% level. This coe? cient captures complementarities in consumption and represents the fraction of city-level consumption that enters the utility function as the reference level to which the household compares itself. To meaningfully interpret the quanti- tative e? ect of this variable, I find it necessary to perform some scaling procedures, since individual consumption is considerably more volatile than is the city-level one. I scale city-level consumption by the ratio of the standard deviations of individual and city-level consumption. The strength of the external habit is 0.29 in the specification reported in Column IV and ranges between 0.258 and 0.295 in the other columns of the table.6 Acoe? cient of zero would imply that the HH is not influenced by the consumption of its neighbors and the model would collapse to the standard model used in the literature. A coe? cient of one would mean that the HH cares only about the way its consumption compares to the neighbors? and not about the absolute level. The strength of internal habit is also very high: the coe? cient on past household consump- tion growth is 0.503, which is significant at the 1% level. These findings provide empirical micro foundations to the theories that explain macroeconomic facts and the equity premium puzzle by introducing habit persistence in the utility function. Although, market incompleteness and hetero- geneity don?t permit to compare this coe? cient directly to those in the representative agent models, it is interesting that the coe? cients are of the same order of magnitude required in Constantinides (1990) and Campbell and Cochrane (1999) to explain the equity premium puzzle, and in Boldrin et al. (2001) to explain output persistency. A natural question is what drives the discrepancy between my findings and Dynan?s (2000). The di? erences between the two studies are many: the measure of consumption used, food vs. credit-card expenditures, the annual versus quarterly frequency of observation, the di? erent 6 I note that a variation of this procedure scales ? C i,t by the ratio of the standard deviations of each HH con- sumption growth rate and its reference group?s consumption growth rate. The external habit coe? cient is slightly lower, but continues to be statistically significant at the 5% level. Alternatively, I standardize the city-level consump- tion growth rate and obtain a habit coe? cient with the same statistical significance and an even higher economic significance than those obtained with the two procedures outlined above. 14 estimation equation, which in her case doesn?t take the variation of the interest rates into account, and the instrument set. In particular, Dynan uses the second lag of income, hours worked and job loss as instruments, while I use the second lag of local unemployment rate, the inflation rate, aggregate income growth rate, mortgage rate, and some individual financial variables. Table VII presents an attempt to compare the two studies. Columns I, II and III show that neither the annual frequency nor the HH specific interest rates seem to cause the di? erence, since simply re-estimating (3.7) with my data annualized or assuming constant interest rates still generates economically and statistically significant coe? cients on the internal habit parameter. On the contrary, Column IV shows that excluding the household-specific financial variables from the instrument set, generates a drop from 0.60 to 0.10 in the internal habit coe? cient, although the coe? cient is still statistically significant. Panel B of Table VII shows that both the partial R2s and the F tests of the first- stage regressions are higher and safe from the Stock and Yogo (2002)?s critique when financial variables are among the instruments. These results indicate that the di? erent findings stem from the availability of HH specific financial information. Another result of the paper is my finding that households respond to the price of consumption. The availability of household-specific borrowing rates and financial information allows to study the sensitivity of consumption to individual-specific interest rate. Iestimatethattheshort run elasticity of consumption to the borrowing rate, R C , is -1.876, which is statistically significant at the 1% level. Previous studies had di? culties in getting precise estimates of this parameter, as they were forced to use the after tax risk-free rate, which by nature displays very limited cross sectional variability. The magnitude is consistent with the results of Gross and Souleles (2002), who estimate that the elasticity of debt, and therefore consumption, to the borrowing rate is -1.3. The coe? cient on the risk-free rate represents the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution (EIS). The estimates indicate that an increase of one percentage point in the risk free rate leads on average to an increase of 0.765% in the consumption growth rate. As in most of the literature, due to the small amount of cross sectional variation exhibited by this variable, I cannot precisely measure the e? ect. Nevertheless, the value of the coe? cient is very similar to those obtained in previous studies of individual consumption choices. For some very common specifications of the utility function the inverse of the EIS constitutes the coe? cient of relative risk aversion. This variable measures the curvature of the value function, which can be interpreted as the willingness to substitute consumption across di? erent states of nature. When this is the case the results imply acoe? cient of risk aversion of 1.31, which is reasonable based on the range of values found by other 15 micro-level studies and surveys. Consistent with the predictions of economic theory, the coe? cients on age and age squared indicate that consumption exhibits a hump-shaped path over the life cycle. I include occupa- tion dummies in the regression, although they are imprecisely measured. Among them, particu- larly interesting is the positive, although not significant, e? ect on consumption growth of being self-employed. Since this group can be using the credit card for business related expenses, as a robustness check I re-estimate all the regressions, this time discarding households headed by a self-employed individual and find that the results do not change. Column IV also shows that the e? ect of home ownership and income bracket on consumption growth is negative, although it is so small as to be almost indistinguishable from zero. I can interpret these findings as mild evidence of precautionary savings or liquidity constraints: households that own a house or which are in a higher income bracket have less need to save for a rainy day and they face fewer limitations on the amount of funds they can borrow. Consequently, they are better able to smooth consumption and, on average, exhibit a lower consumption growth rate. The Hansen J statistics of overidentifying restrictions confirms the validity of the instru- ments in all the specifications. Further, to make sure that the household-specific instruments are orthogonal to the error term, I compute an additional di? erence-in-Sargan statistic for this group of instruments. Again, the hypothesis of orthogonality is not rejected. Nonetheless, a too large instrument set could decrease the power of the overidentifying restrictions tests and also bias the coe? cients toward the inconsistent ordinary least square estimates. I note that this e? ect would bias the results against finding habit persistence, because due to measurement error, the OLS coef- ficients are biased toward zero. In Table VIII, I re-estimate the equation by progressively reducing the number of instruments, to the point in which the system is just identified. For comparison, column I reproduces the first column of Table VI. In Column II, I eliminate the marginal tax rate from the instrument set illustrated above. In Column III I further eliminate the unemployment rate; in Column IV the inflation rate; in Column V all but one lag of aggregate income; in column VI the amount charged o? . Finally, in Column VII, I eliminate the automatic credit-line increases. The resulting instrument set exactly identifies the system and is comprised of the first available lag of the mortgage rate, the state-level income growth, the household debt growth rate and the credit-constrained indicator. Among these variables the instrument that is most relevant for the prediction of city-level aggregate consumption is the mortgage rate, followed by local unemployment and inflation rate. The coe? cientonincomegrowthrateisstatisticallysignificant, but extremely 16 small. The results of this test are very encouraging, because the coe? cients on ? C t , ? c t ? 1 and R C either remain approximately the same or increase slightly, and continue to be statistically sig- nificant.7 The coe? cient that is most sensitive to the reduction of the instrument set is that on the risk-free interest rate, which is sometimes negative, even though very close to zero. However, this coe? cient is very imprecisely measured. Also, I report the R 20 sfromthefirst stage regressions for Table VI at the bottom. The value of the adjusted R 2s are very good. The F statistic shows that the coe? cients on the instruments are statistically di? erent from zero and way outside the critical values indicated by Stock and Yogo (2002) in relation to concerns of weak instruments. The external habit variable in some of the regressions presents an exception. The value of the F tests are way outside of the critical interval required by traditional theory, but they are sometimes too low to dismiss the possibility that the variable is weakly instrumented. 4 Robustness Checks A central focus of the social interaction literature is finding out why people who belong to the same group behave similarly. Manski (1993) identifies three distinct reasons why it could happen: the people in the group face the same shocks, they have similar characteristics, which lead them to behave similarly, and social interactions. Given the data usually available to the econometrician, the identification of the mechanisms at work in the various situations is often problematic. De- spite the use of lagged information to instrument for the contemporaneous city-level consumption growth rate, there might still be questions about the endogeneity of this variable. To address this issue, I analyze the e? ect of a strictly exogenous random change in the external reference point of the household: the event that somebody in the city wins the lottery. I merge the data set with information about lottery winnings from the California lottery and repeat the estimates reported in Table VI but now I drop the city-level information from the instrument set, since the city consump- tion does not enter the estimation equation anymore and use a lottery dummy instead. Table IX shows that the coe? cient on the lottery dummy is economically and statistically significant across all the specifications. The other coe? cients are similar to those in Table VI. If we interpret the lottery dummy as a proxy for the change in the reference points, then the coe? cient indicates that the fraction of city-level consumption that enters the utility function of the household is approxi- mately 0.22. The estimation equation also includes the lag of the lottery dummy, which displays 7 These results are not due to a particular choice of which instruments to drop. Results available upon request show the robustness of the findings to changes in the instrument set. 17 a negative, although not statistically significant, coe? cient. To investigate this aspect further, I re-estimate all the regressions in Table IX without the lagged dummy. I obtain a coe? cient of 0.13 for the contemporaneous dummy, which is statistically significant at the 5% level. These findings provide complementary evidence on the e? ect of social comparisons on consumption decisions. I note that these two measures of the consumption of the external reference group most likely have e? ect through di? erent mechanisms. In the case of city-level consumption what matters for the HH is the average of the reference group, while in the case of the lottery, it is the consumption of one outlier, like the e? ect that the lifestyle of celebrities can have on common people?s consumption. Another concern is that unobservable aggregate shocks might a? ect the results and generate biases due to the short time dimension of the panel. In column VI of Table XI, I add time dummies to the estimation equation to address the case in which I can decompose the shock into economy- wide and idiosyncratic shocks. However, Mariger and Shaw (1993) show that if these shocks hit di? erenthouseholdstoadi? erent extent, time dummies do not address the issue. The reason is that when there is an unexpected shock, HHs make common errors in predicting future income. As a consequence, surprise changes in income, and therefore consumption today, are correlated with lagged changes in income (and lagged consumption). In the consumption context the story could go this way. Suppose everybody expects a recession that does not happen. It is likely that the lower the predicted income change, the higher will be the surprise. This mechanism generates a negative correlation between prediction and surprise that goes against finding habit formation. Nevertheless, I check for the stability of the coe? cients across the major occupations in the data set, as occupation is one of the main reasons why di? erent economic agents might be a? ected di? erently by macroeconomic shocks. Table X reports the results. The coe? cient on the internal habit parameter is statistically significant in five out of six cases and is also very stable, ranging between 0.425 and 0.546. Following Runkle (1991), I also directly test for the presence of these aggregate shocks by including year dummies in the regression. I check whether they are valid instruments by looking at the di? erence in the J statistics from the estimation with and without these dummies. The di? erence is distributed as a ? 23 and is equal to 7.817. From this evidence I conclude I cannot reject the null hypothesis of no aggregate shocks. This evidence reduces my concern that aggregate shocks are the source of the findings. I further investigate the possibility that the findings are a? ected by an omitted variable problem. Such problem might causes city-level consumption growth to influence household behavior simply because it captures some measure of economic activity that helps households predict their income. 18 In other words, I am concerned that the results constitute another facet of the "excess sensitivity" of consumption to income documented by Flavin (1981), Campbell and Mankiw (1989) and the many studies thereafter. To exclude this possibility, I add both the current and future growth rate of income to the Euler equation and perform a horse race between city-level consumption and income. Unfortunately, my data doesn?t contain household-specific income evolution, and therefore I use California state income instead. Column I and II of Table XI show that the coe? cient on the external habit variable is unchanged and significant at the 5% level, while income is not statistically significant (p-value=0.319 and 0.434, respectively). The first stage regressions exclude the possibility that this result is due to income being poorly instrumented, since the adjusted R 2 for the income regression is 0.698. Although it seems reasonable that aggregate income is a better proxy for individual income than are city sales, perhaps the smaller information contained in the sales is orthogonal to that contained in aggregate income and therefore relevant in forming expectations. Encouragingly, Attanasio and Weber (1995) find that once demographic variables and labor choice are accounted for, individual income doesn?t enter the Euler equation in a significant way. While indicative, these arguments alone are unconvincing: for example, Lusardi (1996) using micro data finds evidence of excess sensitivity, so the debate is still open. For this reason, using the PSID, I directly investigate whether city sales provide any information about household income once state income is available: ? lnincome indiv idual,it = ? + ? 1? lnI N C OM E state ? lev el,it +? 2? lnC city ? lev el,it + ? 3ag e i + ? 4ag e 2i + ? it (4.1) I also include in the regression dummy variables that capture marital status, occupational choice, seasonal fluctuations and homeownership. The null hypothesis is that once I control for state income, the coe? cient on city sales is small and not statistically significant. Table XII confirms this hypothesis and suggests that the reason why income is not significant in Table IX cannot be ascribed to the fact that I use state rather than individual income. Some caution should be exercised in interpreting these results since the time period analyzed spans only from 1997 to 2001. Nevertheless, the various pieces of evidence presented above, taken together, seem to indicate that city-level consumption doesn?t proxy for individual income.8 To further control for local economic activity, in column III and IV of Table XI, I add to the regression the variation in city-level 8 Similar regressions using the growth rate of individual wealth as the dependent variable provide evidence that city-level consumption doesn?t proxy for this variable either. 19 unemployment rate and median zip code house value and rent: these variables are neither economically nor statistically significant, while the habit persistence coe? cients are stable and statistically significant.Again, the result is not driven by poor instruments for city unemployment rate, since the adjusted R 2 of the first stage regression is 0.84. In column V of Table XI, I investigate the e? ect of changing the specification and addanextra lag of household own consumption to the regression. I am interested to see the e? ect ofhow this simplification on a? ects the estimates, since HH consumption exhibits autocorrelation over time. The coe? cient on the second lag of HH consumption growth is statistically significant, although not very big. Most important, the coe? cient on the first lag of consumption growth decreases only slightly (from 0.503 to 0.453), while the one on city-level consumption actually increases, and the statistical significance is the same. Results (available upon request) also indicate that my findings are robust to changes in the instrument set beyond those reported in Table VIII,andtotheinclusionintheregressionof various measures of household financial conditions, as the growth rate of debt, and balance transfers indicators. Column VII of Table XI contains, as an illustrative example, the estimates obtained by adding the household-specificdebtgrowthrateto the regression, which confirms the results. I note that the measure of consumption is not a? ected by the presence of balance transfers on the credit card, because I separately identify and exclude these sums. However, it could be that HHs that make balance transfers behave di? erently from others in ways that the variables in the regression cannot control. This robustness test controls for that possibility. 5 Alternative Explanations of the Results Alternative explanations for my findings include the presence of liquidity constraints, precautionary saving motives, and learning about one?s own income profile. These phenomena, like internal habit formation, cause consumption to adjust slowly to predictable changes in income, and therefore induce positive correlation between current and lagged consumption growth rates. Liquidity constraints consist in borrowing interest rates that are higher than the lending rates and quantity constraints on the amount of funds that an HH can borrow. I can control for both of these aspects in the current setting. One way to test for the presence of liquidity constraints consists in splitting the sample between unconstrained and credit constrained households. For this purpose, I build a measure of the tightness of liquidity constraints based on the ratio of unpaid balance to the 20 credit limit. Figure II plots the frequency distribution of this indicator and shows that the majority of the observations display quite low credit usage, most of the times due to the very high credit limit they enjoy. Nevertheless, some cases of very high usage and therefore binding credit constraints are present in the data. Column I and II of Table XIII contain the results of estimating the baseline regression on subsamples constituted by the lowest and highest quartile of the credit constrained indicator distribution. The lowest quartile subsample contains the unconstrained HHs for whom the credit constraint measure is zero; while the highest quartile subsample contains the liquidity constrained households, for which the measure is above 0.76. If liquidity constraints are the cause of the correlation between current and lagged household consumption growth rate, I would expect to see that the past consumption growth rate matters only in the highly constrained subsample. The estimates indicate that this is not the case.The magnitude of the internal habit coe? cient is similar and highly significant statistically in both subsamples: 0.565 in the unconstrained sample, and 0.557 in the liquidity constrained sample. The results are robust to the choice of other cuto? points. The inclusion of the lagged growth rate of state income in each of the subsample regressions confirms that income is not economically nor statistically significant (columns III and IV of Table XIII, respectively). Nevertheless, it slightly decreases the coe? cient on the internal habit parameter in the unconstrained case and increases it in the constrained one. This result indicates some sign of liquidity constraints, although they are not strong enough to dismiss the e? ect of habit persistence. Another interesting result from column I is that keeping up with the Joneses is a phenomenon typical of higher-income HHs, who are over-represented in the unconstrained group. Another consequence of binding liquidity constraints is that the HH cannot set the consump- tion at the optimal level. Therefore I will observe that consumption is too low today relative to tomorrow, and that the lagged income growth rate is negatively related to current consumption growth (Zeldes (1989)). Column V of Table XIII shows that when I include the lagged state income growth rate in the regression, the coe? cient of the internal habit parameter equals 0.502, similar to 0.503 in the baseline regression, and is statistically significant at the one percent level. On the contrary, the coe? cient on the income growth rate doesn?t have the expected negative sign and cannot be statistically distinguished from zero. I present a further robustness test in Column VI. This test consists of adding the credit- constrained indicator directly in the regression, where it acts as a proxy of the Lagrange multiplier on the borrowing constraint. The coe? cient on this variable has the expected sign, although it is not significantly di? erent than zero. This indicator is increasing in the level of credit line us- 21 age and therefore should display an increasing relationship with the unobserved shadow price of resources. Since it is not possible to directly test this assertion these results should be considered only indicative. All the tests discussed above suggest that the presence of liquidity constraints does not explain away the results. The precautionary motives story has implications that are very similar to the liquidity constraints model, and the tests of the significance of lagged income growth and splitting of the sample contained in column I to V of Table XIII speaks to this alternative as well. HHs that have low resources available and uncertain future prospects save more and therefore display a higher growth rate of consumption from one period to the next, much like liquidity constrained HHs. Following Dynan (1993) and Carroll (1997), I also add the square of household consumption growth rate to the regression, to capture future household-specific uncertainty. To address Carroll?s concerns about the validity of group-specific instruments, I include in the instrument set individual variables proxying for household resources, such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged o? , automatic credit line changes, and a credit constrained indicator. Column VII of Table XIII shows that the coe? cient on the square of consumption innovations is neither economically nor statistically significant and its presence in the regression doesn?t a? ect the estimates of the habit persistence parameters or the interest rates sensitivities. The latter test also addresses the hypothesis that consumption reacts slowly to expected income changes because the HH learns whether the change is permanent or temporary. To the extent that more volatile consumption indicates more uncertain income and thus more scope for learning,we should expect higher consumption growth rates for HHs with more volatile ? c it .ColumnVIIshows that the data do not bear out this hypothesis. 6 Aggregate Implications of the Micro Findings In addition to characterizing household preferences, does habit persistence matter in the aggregate? And can the representative agent model capture this phenomenon? I investigate this issue by aggregating the micro data, with the caveat that, given the relatively short time dimension of the panel, the results are only suggestive. Leaving aside the statistical problems of the per-capita-consumption series (Wilcox (1992), Dynan (2000)), the representative agent framework does not capture heterogenous information sets, finite lives, and liquidity constraints. These factors cause the marginal rate of substitution 22 (MRS) to di? er across agents and, unless very restrictive conditions are met, the estimates of the preference parameters obtained with such models can be severely biased. While in the theory, there are contrasting conclusions on whether these biases arise, the empirical work on aggregation issues unanimously indicates the crucial importance of accounting for heterogeneity. Brav et al. (2002) show that in order to obtain plausible asset pricing implications the stochastic discount factor needs to be constructed as a weighted average of individual MRS. Attanasio and Weber (1993) illustrate how correct aggregation matters for estimating the EIS and the excess sensitivity of consumption to income.9 Exploiting the household-level data, I can estimate the Euler equations using a weighted average of the individual MRS that takes heterogeneity and non linearities into account: ? 1N NX i =1 (ln c i,t )=? + ? ? 1N NX i =1 (ln c i,t ? 1)+R ft + ? t (6.1) but also using the per capita MRS, as in the representative agent framework: ? ln ? 1 N NX i =1 c i,t ! = ? + ? ? ln ? 1 N NX i =1 c i,t ? 1 ! + R ft + ? t (6.2) where c i,t is household consumption, and R ft is the risk-free rate.10 Table XIV contains the estimates from (6.1) and (6.2). As in the micro-level regressions, household consumption and the risk free rate are treated as endogenous and instrumented with the second lag of income growth rate, average mortgage rate, and unemployment rate. Column I shows that when estimating the per capita regression (6.2) there is no evidence of habit persistence: the coe? cient on past consumption growth rate is actually negative, albeit not statistically di? erent from zero. Columns II and III illustrate that the estimates display signs of excess sensitivity of consumption to income. A di? erent picture arises when the properly aggregated quantities are used. Column IV reports the results of the estimation of (6.1). The habit persistence coe? cient is now equal to 0.515 and it is statistically significant at the 5% level. This number is quite sizeable, and 9 In the theoretical literature, Mankiw (1986) and Constantinides and Du? e (1996) show that in the presence of idiosyncratic income shocks the Euler equations don?t depend only on the growth rate of consumption, but also on its cross sectional variability. On the contrary, Krusell and Smith (1998), show, using calibrations, that in a setting with transitory idiosyncratic income shocks the mean of the wealth distribution is enough to describe the macroeconomic aggregates. 10Since, by definition, the representative agent framework is populated only by one consumer, the di? erence between internal and external reference point dissipates and only the dependence of current consumption growth on last period growth can be tested. 23 suggests that, once the correct measure of consumption is used, there is evidence of habit formation also at the aggregate level. Tests of excess sensitivity, reported in Columns V and VI, display no sign of it, using either the contemporaneous or lagged income growth rate. The Hansen J statistic indicates that the overidentifying restrictions don?t reject the model, but has low power, due to the relatively big number of instruments in comparison to the number of observations available. I have therefore performed some robustness checks by changing the instrument set and found that the habit persistence coe? cient is relatively stable when the properly aggregated measure is used, while it varies from -0.8 to 0.15, and it is never significant, when per capita consumption is analyzed. Although the short time period analyzed makes these findings only indicative, it is striking that they show a big discrepancy between the two procedures. What are the reasons for this di? erence? Attanasio and Weber (1993) show that, for any distribution of consumption growth, the di? erence between ? 1N PNi =1 (lnc i,t ) and ? ln ? 1 N PN i =1 c i,t ? represents the change in the Theil?s measure of entropy and can be approximated by the first four central moments of the cross sectional distribution: ? Theil = ? E i lnc i,t ? ? ln (E i c i,t )=? ln ? 1+12? 2,t + 16? 3,t + 124? 4,t ? + e (6.3) where ? k,t represents the kth central moment and e is an approximation residual. If the cross sectional moments of consumption growth rates change over time, the two measures will move in an asynchronous way and the per capita regression will be biased. Figure III, panel A, shows the evolution of E i ln c i,t and ln (E i c i,t ) over time. As the economy slows down, both measures of aggregate consumption fall, but the di? erence between them widens. Fig. III, panel B, confirms that the two series not only diverge in levels, but have also di? erent growth rates, which causes marginal utilities to di? er. To further investigate the origins of the di? erences, Figure IV plots each of the higher moments of the cross sectional distribution of household consumption included in (6.3): the cross sectional standard deviation of consumption growth displays a strong seasonal pattern (Panel A), the skewness is always positive and tends to increase as time passes and the economy gets deeper into recession (Panel B), and the distribution evolves from fairly flat to quite peaked (Panel C). Following Attanasio and Weber (1993b), Abel and Eberly (2002), columns VII to IX of Table XIV report the results of adding to the regression cross sectional standard deviation, the skewness and the kurtosis, respectively, to see whether this reduces the bias. The estimates indicate that adding these moments strongly improves the significance of the EIS, but has no 24 e? ect on uncovering the habit persistence revealed by the micro data. These results suggest that omitted demographic variables and other measures of heterogeneity also play a very important role. Unfortunately, it is not possible to check directly the e? ects of omitting these variables in the aggregate regression. 7Conclusions In this paper I use a novel data set on the credit-card expenditures of a representative sample of U.S. households to investigate whether household preferences exhibit habit formation. The estimation results provide support for this hypothesis: I find that the strength of the exter- nal habit, captured by the fraction of the consumption of the reference group that enters the utility function, is 0.290; while the strength of internal habit, represented by household past consumption, is 0.503. My results are robust to the inclusion of various measures of economic activity in the regression, tests for the presence of aggregate shocks, liquidity constraints, precautionary saving motives, and learning. The results are also confirmed by the use of lottery winnings in the city as an independent exogenous measure of the change in the reference point. Another result is the finding that households respond to the price of consumption. I estimate the short run elasticity of consumption to the borrowing rate at -1.876, which is statistically significant at the 1% level. An open issue is whether the results generalize to a more comprehensive measure of consump- tion. Unfortunately, there are no statistics available on the type of goods bought with credit cards, so I am unable to check whether these HHs are more likely to exhibit habit formation or to display status. And yet, the analysis in Section 2 shows that this measure of consumption displays the same features that we would expect to see in overall consumption. Further the statistics on payment methods illustrate the exponential pervasiveness of credit-card payments. Another question is whether we can distinguish internal habit formation from adjustment costs. Gabaix and Laibson (2002) build a model based on adjustment costs. Their model shows aggregate implications that are observationally equivalent to habit persistence. The individual behavior be- hind these dynamics is however one of infrequent adjustments that in the micro data would generate a negative, rather than a positive, coe? cient on the lagged consumption growth. Nevertheless, it is always possible to model the adjustment costs in a di? erent way and develop a setting that is observationally equivalent to internal habit. For example, quadratic adjustment costs would gen- erate these results. However, while this type of adjustment costs is intuitively appealing for firms 25 making capital investments, it is not clear why a consumer should face psychological or physical costs that would induce her to buy something in installments of increasing amounts over time. On the contrary, search costs and the cost of processing information or paying attention would lead to a framework similar to that of Gabaix and Laibson (2002).11 While these remarks are suggestive, one would like to directly test this hypothesis; unfortunately, very detailed data on good purchased and possibly survey evidence would be necessary to address this question. Finally and most important, these findings provide micro evidence in support of the theories that explain macroeconomic and asset pricing phenomena by introducing habit persistence in the utility function. Most of this work is based on a representative agent framework, and although a direct parallel between the magnitude of the coe? cients cannot be made, my findings are line with those the theoretical models require for habit persistence to explain the macroeconomic and asset pricing phenomena in question. However, most important for policy making, and to understand what drives consumption, saving and financial investments decisions, is that these preferences are not the artifact of aggregation, but rather a feature of the decision making by the households in the economy. The results in this paper suggest that this is the case. A related question is whether these phenomena matter in the aggregate. Section 6 indicates that, once I aggregate individual consumption choices properly, and take into account heterogeneity and nonlinearity of marginal utility, habit persistence is present at the aggregate level as well. Theoretical investigation of the aggregate implications of heterogenous households exhibiting habit persistence and facing liquidity constraints is an important task for future research. References [1] Abel, Andrew B. (1990), "Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, pp. 38-42. [2] Abel, Andrew B. (1999), "Risk Premia and Term Premia in General Equilibrium." Journal of Monetary Economics,Vol.43,No.1,p.3-33. [3] Abel, Andrew B., and Eberly, Janice C. (2002), "Investment and q with Fixed Costs: An Empirical Analysis," Working Paper. [4] Attanasio, Orazio, and Browning, Martin. (1993a) "Consumption over the Life Cycle and over the Business Cycle." The American Economic Review, Vol. 85, No. 5, pp. 1118-1137. [5] Attanasio, Orazio, and Weber, Guglielmo. (1993b), "Consumption Growth, the Interest Rate and Aggregation" TheReviewofEconomicStudies, Vol. 60, No. 3, pp. 631-649. 11If we consider liquidity constraints as sui generis adjustment costs, we would indeed get positive autocorrelation in consumption growth rates. Section 6 indicates that despite liquidity constraints are important for some householdes they are not teh source of the results. 26 [6] Attanasio, Orazio, and Weber, Guglielmo. (1995), "Is Consumption Growth Consistent with Intertemporal Optimization? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey." The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, No. 6, pp. 1121-1157. [7] Ausubel, Lawrence. (1999) "Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market,? Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Maryland. [8] Bertrand, Marianne, Luttmer, Erzo, F. P., and Mullainathan, Sendhil, (2000) "Network E? ects and Welfare Cultures," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, no. 3, pp. 1019-1055. [9] Boldrin, Michele, Christiano, Lawrence J., and Fisher, Jonas D.M. (2001) "Habit Persistence, Asset Returns and the Business Cycle." American Economic Review, Vol. 91, pp. 149-166. [10] Brav, Alon, Constantinides, George M., and Geczy, Christopher C. (2002), "Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers and Limited Participation: Empirical Evidence." The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 110, No. 4, pp. 793-824. [11] Browning, Martin, and Lusardi, Annamaria. (1996), "Household Saving: Micro Theories and Micro Facts." Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34, pp. 1797-1855. [12] Brunnermeier, Markus, and Nagel, Stefan. (2005), "Do Wealth Fluctuations Generate Time- Varying Risk Aversion? Micro-Evidence on Individuals? Asset Allocation," Working Paper. [13] Campbell, John Y., and Cochrane, John H. (1999), "By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior." The Journal of Political Economy,Vol. 107, No. 2, pp. 205-251. [14] Campbell, John Y., and Mankiw, Gregory N. (1989), "Consumption, Income and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence." in O.J. Blanchard and S. Fischer (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, Cambridge, Mass. MIT Press, pp. 185-216. [15] Campbell, John Y., and Shiller, Robert J. (1988) "Stock Prices, Earnings, and Expected Dividends." The Journal of Finance, Vol. 43, pp. 661-676. [16] Carroll, Christopher D. (1997), ?Bu? er-Stock Saving and the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis,? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, no. 1, pp. 1-56. [17] Carroll, Christopher D., Overland, Jody R., and Weil, David N. (2000) "Saving and Growth with Habit Formation,? American Economic Review, 90(3), 341-355. [18] Case, Anne, and Katz, Lawrence F. (1991), "The Company You Keep: The E? ects of Family and Neighborhood on Disadvantaged Youths." NBER Working Paper No. W3705. [19] Chamberlain, Gary. (1984), "Panel Data," in Z. Griliches and M.D. Intriligator (eds.), Hand- book of Econometrics, Vol. 2, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp.1247-1318. [20] Chen, Xiaohong, and Ludvigson, Sydney C. (2003), "Land of Addicts? An Empirical Investi- gation of Habit-Based Asset Pricing Models," Working Paper. [21] Constantinides, George M. (1990), "Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle." The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 3, pp. 519-543. [22] Constantinides, George M., and Du? e, Darrell. (1996), "Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers." The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 104, No. 2, pp. 219-240. [23] Davis, Steven J., Kubler, Felix, and Willen, Paul. (2004), "Borrowing Costs and the Demand forEquityovertheLifecycle,"WorkingPaper. [24] Deaton, Angus. (1992), Understanding Consumption. Oxford: Clarendon Press ; New York : Oxford University Press. 27 [25] Duesenberry, James S. (1949), Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior,Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. [26] Dupor, Bill, and Liu, Fang. (2003), "Jealousy and Equilibrium Overconsumption." The Amer- ican Economic Review, Vol. 93, No. 1, pp. 423-428. [27] Dynan, Karen E. (1993), "How Prudent are Consumers?" The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, No. 6, pp. 1104-1113. [28] Dynan, Karen E. (2000), "Habit Formation in Consumer Preferences: Evidence from Panel Data." The American Economic Review, Vol. 90, No. 3, pp. 391-406. [29] Eichenbaum, Martin S., Hansen, Lars P., and Singleton, Kenneth J. (1988), "A Time Se- ries Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and Leisure Choice Under Uncertainty." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 103, pp. 51-78. [30] Ferson, Wayne E., and Constantinides, George M. (1991), "Habit Persistence and Durability in Aggregate Consumption: Empirical Tests." Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 29, pp.199-240. [31] Flavin, Marjorie. (1981), "The Adjustment of Consumption to Changing Expectations About Future Income." The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89, No. 5, pp. 974-1009. [32] Frank, Robert H. (2005), "Positional Externalities Cause Large and Preventable Welfare Losses." The American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 95, No. 2, pp. 137-141. [33] Fuhrer, Je? rey C., (2000), "Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model with Habit Formation.? FRB Boston Series, paper no. 00-5. [34] Gabaix, Xavier, and Laibson, David. (2002) "The 6D Bias and the Equity Premium Puzzle" in Benjamin Bernanke and Kenneth Rogo? ed., NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol.16, p. 257-312. [35] Gerdes, Geo? rey R., and Walton, Jack K. II, (2002), "The Use of Checks and Other Noncash Payment Instrument in the United States." Federal Reserve Bulletin, pp. 360-374. [36] Grinblatt, Mark, Keloharju, Matti, and Ikaheimo, Seppo. (2004), "Interpersonal E? ects in Consumption: Evidence from the Automobile Purchases of Neighbors." NBER Working Paper 10226. [37] Gross, David B., and Souleles, Nicholas S. (2002), "Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data" The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 1, pp. 149-186. [38] Harvey, Campbell R. (1989), "Time-Varying Conditional Covariances in Tests of Asset Pricing Models." The Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 289-317. [39] Hayashi, Fumio. (1985a), "The E? ect of Liquidity Constraints on Consumption: A Cross- Sectional Analysis." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100, No. 1, pp. 183-206. [40] Hayashi, Fumio (1985b). "The Permanent Income Hypothesis and Consumption Durability: Analysis Based on Japanese Panel Data." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100, No. 4, pp. 1083-1113. [41] Heaton, John. (1995), "An Empirical Investigation of Asset Pricing with Temporally Depen- dent Preference Specifications." Econometrica, Vol. 63, No. 3, pp. 681-717. [42] Hong, Harrison, Kubik, Je? rey D., and Stein, Jeremy C. (2004), "Social Interactions and Stock-Market Participation." The Journal of Finance, Vol. 49, no. 1, pp. 137-163. 28 [43] Krusell, Per, and Smith, Anthony. (1998) "Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macro- economy" The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106, No. 5, pp. 867-896. [44] Laibson, David, Repetto, Andrea, and Tobacman, Jeremy. (2000), "A Debt Puzzle," Working Paper, Harvard University. [45] Lim, Paul J., and Benjamin, Matthew. (2001) "Digging Your Way Out of Debt," U.S. News and World Report. [46] Lupton, Joseph P. (2003), "Household Portfolio Choice and the Habit Liability: Evidence from Panel Data." Working Paper, Federal Reserve Board. [47] Lusardi, Annamaria. (1996), "Permanent Income, Current Income, and Consumption: Evi- dence from Two Panel Data Sets." Journal of Business Economics and Statistics, Vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 81-90. [48] Luttmer, Erzo, F.P. (2005), "" Neighbors as Negatives: Relative Earnings and Well-Being," Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 120, No. 3, pp. 963-1002. [49] Mankiw, Gregory N. (1986), "The Equity Premium Puzzle and the Concentration of Aggregate Shocks." Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 17, pp. 211-219. [50] Manski, Charles F. (1993), "Identification of Endogenous Social E? ects: The Reflection Prob- lem." TheReviewofEconomicStudies, Vol. 60, No. 3, pp. 531-542. [51] Mariger, Randall P., and Shaw, Kathryn. (1993), "Unanticipated Aggregate Disturbances and Tests of the Life-Cycle Consumption Model Using Panel Data." The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75, No. 1, pp. 48-56 [52] Muellbauer, John N.J. (1988), "Habits, Rationality and Myopia in the Life Cycle Consumption Function" Annales d?Economie et de Statistique, Vol. 9, pp. 47-70. [53] Runkle, David E. (1991), "Liquidity Constraints and the Permanent-Income Hypothesis." Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 27, pp. 73-98. [54] Shore, Stephen H. and White, Joshua S., (2002) "External Habit Formation and the Home Bias Puzzle" Working Paper. [55] Stock, James H., and Yogo, Motohiro, (2002), "Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression." NBER Working Paper, No. T0284. [56] Veblen, Thorstein. (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class. An Economic Study of Institutions, Random House. [57] Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette. (2002), "Limited Asset Market Participation and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution." The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 110, No. 4, pp. 825-853. [58] Wilcox, David W. (1992), "The Construction of U.S. Consumption Data: Some Facts and Their Implications for Empirical Work." The American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4, pp. 922-941. [59] Zeldes, Stephen P. (1989), "Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investiga- tion" The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, No. 2, pp. 305-346. [60] Zinman, Jonathan. (2004) ?Why Use Debit Instead of Credit? Consumer Choice in a Trillion Dollar Market.? Working Paper. 29 Fig. I Panel A Panel B Fig. I ? Plot of average quarterly credit-card expenditures against age (Panel A) and income bracket (Panel B). Consumption over the life cycle 0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 18 28 38 48 58 68 78 88 98 Age Quarterly Consumption Relationship between Consumption and Income 380 480 580 680 780 880 980 1080 0246810 Income Bracket Quarterly Consumptio n Fig II Fig . II ? Frequency distribution of the credit-constrained indicator. This variable is calculated as the ratio between unpaid balance and credit line. Distribution of credit usage 58.21% 6.77% 3.93% 2.98% 2.85% 2.53% 2.80% 3.17% 3.37% 7.23% 6.16% 0% 10 % 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% <0.10 0.10-0.20 0.20-0.30 0.30-0.40 0.40-0.50 0.50-0.60 0.60-0.70 0.70-0.80 0.80-0.90 0.90-1.00 >1.00 Credit-Constrained Indicator Fig. III Panel A Correctly aggregated and per-capita aggregate consumption 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 qdate 1999q4 2000q1 2000q2 2000q3 2000q4 2001q1 2001q2 2001q3 2001q4 2002q1 2002q2 Panel B Growth rates of correctly aggregated and per-capita aggregate consumption -0.60 -0.40 -0.20 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.60 0.80 1.00 1.20 qdate 1999q4 2000q1 2000q2 2000q3 2000q4 2001q1 2001q2 2001q3 2001q4 2002q1 2002q2 2002q3 Fig. III ? Aggregate consumption series, constructed from the credit card data. The blue line represents the correctly aggregated variable, as in (7.1), and the pink line represents per-capita consumption, as in (7.2). Fig. IV Evolution of standard deviation, skewness and kurtosis of the cross sectional distribution of household consumption growth rates Evolution of the cross sectional standard deviation of household consumption growth 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 qdate 1999q4 2000q1 2000q2 2000q3 2000q4 2001q1 2001q2 2001q3 2001q4 2002q1 2002q2 2002q3 Evolution of the cross sectional skewness of household consumption growth 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 qdate 1999q4 2000q1 2000q2 2000q3 2000q4 2001q1 2001q2 2001q3 2001q4 2002q1 2002q2 2002q3 Evolution of the cross sectional kurtosis of household consumption growth 0.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 qdate 1999q4 2000q1 2000q2 2000q3 2000q4 2001q1 2001q2 2001q3 2001q4 2002q1 2002q2 2002q3 Table I Data Sources and Variables Description Variable Description Source ? cit Household consumption growth rate Amount charged on the credit cardduring the quarter for purchases and cash advances. I construct growth rates by taking the difference in the logarithms of this variable between time t and (t-1) Credit card data set ? Cjt External Reference Point: Citi-level consumption growth rate city level quarterly taxable sales, defined as "the dollar amount of California retail transactions, excluding those transactions specifically exempt from the California Sales and Use tax". This measure excludes prescription medicines, sales of nontaxable items such as some food products consumed at home and prescription medicines, and taxable transactions disclosed by BOE audits. A detail description is available in "Publication Number 61, Sales and Use Taxes: Exemptions and Exclusions" (March 2003). People not living in a city are associated to the nearest one by geographic matching based on distance between zip code's centroids. The average distance between the centroids of the originating and matching point for HHs not living in a city is 1.1 miles, while the median is 0.4 miles. I construct per capita sales by dividing this quantity by the city population available from Current Population Survey at annual intervals. State Board of Equalization (BOE) Financial Variables RCit Household-specific Borrowing Rate Interest charged on the debt outstanding on the credit card, calculated by taking the ratio of the total charges incurred in a period (finance charges, late charges and over the limit charges) to the balance outstanding.. It is different from the stated APR, because it takes into account compounding and the effective period of time over which the money is borrowed. This results in a more accurate measure of the cost of borrowing Credit card data set Rft Risk Free Rate 3-month T-bill rate. It represents the risk free at which the HHs are supposed to invest the funds that are left after paying the balance on the credit card. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (FRED) Credit constrained indicatorit Ratio of debt outstanding to credit limit.It captures credit availability Credit card data set ? debtit Household-specific Debt Growth Rate Amount of the credit card balance unpaid and on which the HH is charged interest. Two measures of debt are considered: debt, which represents the overall debt on the card, including balance transfers from other cards. And debt2, which excludes balance transfers and assumes that of any debt outstanding the HH first repays the newly generated debt and only after that the one transferred from other cards. Credit card data set ? credit_lineit Household total credit limit on the card Credit card data set ? charged_offit Amount charged off. Amount of debt outstanding that the credit card issuer will not be able to recoup and thus writes down as a loss on the account. The reason is bankruptcy, both formally recognized by a court or informal. According to this measure 2.68% of the observations have a positive amount charged off, corresponding to 0.92% of the HHs. Credit card data set Balance Transferit Amount of debt outstanding on another credit card and transferred to this one, or transferred from this card to another. The total number of balance transfers is 562, equal to 1.6% of the observations. The measure of consumption doesn't include balance transfers. Credit card data set Demographic Variables Age Age of the main account holder as of July 1999. Credit card data set Marit_status Dummy variable equal to one if the main account holder is married as of July 1999 Credit card data set Homeowner Dummy variable equal to one if the HH owns the house it lives in. Credit card data set Income bracket Income category the HH belongs to Credit card data set Occupation dummies dummy variables indicating the occupation of the primary card holder Credit card data set Self_empl Dummy variable equal to one if the HH head is self-employed. Credit card data set Marginal Tax Rate Marginal tax rate faced by a family or single individual in a given income bracket Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Zip Code-Level Economic Variables Median House Value Median value of the house for a specific sample of owner-occupied houses in the 2000 U.S. Census. The value is the respondent's estimate of how much the property would sell for if it were for sale. 2000 U.S. Census Median Rent Median rent asked in the zip code area. No adjustment is made for the inclusion of utilities and fuel. 2000 U.S. Census City-Level Economic Variables Mortgage Ratet Average mortgage rate faced by people living in the city in a given quarter. American Chamber of Commerce Research Association (ACCRA) ? ln U_ratet Quarterly average of the monthly MSA level unemployment rate Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Inflation Ratet All Urban Consumers Price Index, base 182:84, not seasonally adjusted. The quantities are deflated using the BLS Consumer Price Index of the MSA to which they belong (Los Angeles, San Francisco-San Jose or the index for the West Region ). Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Lottery Dummy variable equal to one if the HH lives in a city in which there has been a lottery winning in that quarter California Lottery Prop. annuity fraction of the winners who opt to receive the prize in installments, rather than in a lump-sum payment California Lottery Total winnings Total $ winnings in the city where the HH lives, in a given quarter California Lottery State-Level Economic Variables ? lnincomet Growth rate of quarterly per-capita disposable income in current dollars California Department of Finance Table II Summary Statistics Mean Median Std. Dev. Individual Consumption 701.19 114.92 1596.92 growth rate -0.12 0.00 2.73 Aggregate Consumption 2367.22 2239.58 975.53 growth rate 0.01 0.03 0.19 RCit 16.95%0.00%114.65% Rf 3.88%4.42%1.71% Inflation rate 0.79% 0.87% 0.46% DEMOGRAPHIC VARIABLES Age 46 45 15 Marital Status (% married) 44.76% Home Owner (%) 74.88% Marginal Tax Rate 28.44% 28.00% 7.37% CHARACTERISTICS of the CONTRACT Unpaid balance $1,060.05 $0.00 $2,048.60 Credit Line $8,823.51 $10,000.00 $3,733.95 Charged Off $152.33 $0.00 $1,058.07 dummy 0.027 0.000 0.160 Credit-Constrained Indicator 0.33 0.07 0.41 Balance Transfers $132.64 $0.00 $1,004.97 dummy 0.016 0 0.126 ZIP CODE-LEVEL DATA Median House Value $258,980.80 $222,700.00 $146,479.10 Median Income $54,618.55 $50,825.00 $19,602.71 Rent $791.10 $752.00 $245.95 Unemployment Rate 6.33% 5.49% 3.62% CITY-LEVEL DATA Mortgage Rate 7.32% 7.21% 0.59% Unemployment rate 5.07% 4.43% 3.22% Lottery 0.0501906 00.2183412 Prop. Annuity 0.0021785 0 0.0466238 Total winnings 156133.4 0 3095676 STATE-LEVEL DATA Personal Income $26,792.17 $26,906.59 $895.74 Table III Mean and Std. Dev. of Individual Consumption In this Table I compare the mean and standard deviation of my measure of consumption to data from the publicly available data sets traditionally used in the literature: the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) and aggregate data. Credit Card Panel Comparison data set Mean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev. Individual Data All -0.120 2.730 -3.3/3.3 0.005 0.870 -1.1/1.1 -0.002 0.368 0.000 0.32* Cross Sectional Data All 0.014 0.330 -0.01* 0.06* Aggregate Data All 0.000 0.013 0.003*** 0.009*** * Comparison data set: PSID, data from Zeldes (1989) * Comparison data set: CEX, data from Brav et al. (2002) * Comparison data set: aggregate data, from Constantinides et al. (1991) Table IV Aggregate Local Consumption Comparison with NIPA Aggregate Consumption In this table I compare the city-level sales data that I use to construct the measure of the external reference point to the aggregate data traditionally used in the literature: the aggregate consumption from the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA). The main difference between the two measures is the lack of housing services in the California aggregate sales. California Aggregate Sales Non-durables and Services (NIPA) Mean 3674.3945659.72 Median 3669.729 5737 Std. Dev. 402.2181 404.1349 Correlation Coefficient 0.8583 For a definition of the California aggregate sales see Table I Table V Autocorrelations of Household Consumption ? ct ? ct-1 ? ct-2 ? ct-3 ? ct 1 ? ct-1 -0.3863 1 ? ct-2 -0.0281 -0.3866 1 ? ct-3 -0.0212 -0.0317 -0.3914 1 Table VI Basic Estimation In this Table I present the results of the estimation of the Euler equation: ? lnci,t=k1+? 0? lnCi,t+? -1? lnCi,t-1+?? lnci,t-1+? ln(1+(Ri,tf-1)Pr[Yi,tH]) +? ln(1+( Ri,tC 1)1[B])+? 1? agei,t+? 2? agei,t+? i,t Column I estimates the basic model, while columns II to IV progressively add to the specification family composition, home ownership and occupation. The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. (I) (II) (III) (IV) RCt -1.727*** -1.845*** -1.842*** -1.876*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Rft 0.448 0.770 0.765 0.824 (0.537) (0.381) (0.384) (0.349) ? Ct 0.258*** 0.295** 0.294** 0.290** (0.005) (0.024) (0.024) (0.026) ? ct-1 0.530*** 0.501*** 0.502*** 0.503*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) ? Ct-1 0.007 0.014 0.014 0.013 (0.195) (0.176) (0.176) (0.189) Age 0.004 0.004 0.004 (0.334) (0.363) (0.305) Age2 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 (0.141) (0.152) (0.127) marital status 0.022 0.023 0.023 (0.399) (0.375) (0.386) homeowner -0.018 -0.017 -0.017 (0.656) (0.676) (0.668) income bracket -0.003 -0.004 -0.002 (0.524) (0.470) (0.705) self_empl 0.085 0.071 (0.158) (0.252) Occupation dummies Yes Seasonal dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes # Households 2220 1432 1432 1432 Hansen J statistic 8.725 7.712 7.730 7.853 (pvalue) 0.463 0.441 0.562 0.441 C statistic+ 1.021 3.748 3.761 3.747 (pvalue) 0.907 0.563 0.439 0.549 Adj. R-squared 0.214 0.226 0.226 0.225 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% + Instruments tested: lags of debt outstanding, amount charged off, change in credit line and credit constraints measure. A description of the variables is reported in Table I. Instrument set: marginal tax rate, the local unemployment rate, the inflation rate, aggregate disposable income growth rate, mortgage rate, and some individual variables such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged off, automatic credit line changes, and a credit constrained indicator. First Stage Regressions (I) (II) (III) (IV) Adj. R2 Adj. R2 Adj. R2 Adj. R2 RCt 0.0635 0.0602 0.0605 0.0618 Rft 0.9543 0.9543 0.9543 0.9543 ? Ct 0.2351 0.3666 0.3666 0.3661 ? ct-1 0.0281 0.0282 0.0281 0.028 p-value p-value p-value p-value RCt 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Rft 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 ? Ct 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 ? ct-1 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Table VII Comparison with Dynan (2000) This Table illustrates the comparison between my results and Dynan (2000). In particular, I re-estimate the same regression as in Col (V) of Table VI using an annualized measure of credit card consumption and of the other variables: ? lnci,t=k1+? 0? lnCi,t+? -1? lnCi,t-1+?? lnci,t-1+? ln(1+(Ri,tf-1)Pr[Yi,tH]) + ? ln(1+( Ri,tC -1)1[B])+? 1? agei,t+? 2? agei,t+? i,t Col (I) presents the baseline estimation; Col (II) investigates the effect of estimating the above regression without the external habit, as Dynan?s estimation doesn?t contain this variable. Col (III) drops the HH-specific financial variables from the instrument set; while Col (IV) drops the interest rate from the estimation equation, as Dynan considers an Euler equation with constant interest rates. The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. (I) (II) (III) (IV) RCt -0.076 -0.116 -2.100 (0.487) (0.246) (0.352) ? Ct 0.110 0.985*** 1.055*** (0.931) (0.000) (0.000) ? ct-1 0.602 0.662*** 0.139** 0.109 (0.422) (0.000) (0.048) (0.179) Age -0.001 -0.001 0.000 0.007 (0.837) (0.622) (0.910) (0.367) Age2 0.000 0.000 -0.000 -0.000 (0.829) (0.584) (0.872) (0.346) marital status 0.006 -0.000 0.010 0.045 (0.740) (0.974) (0.529) (0.273) self_empl -0.031 -0.031 -0.038 -0.014 (0.519) (0.151) (0.290) (0.839) homeowner -0.001 -0.005 0.006 -0.035 (0.964) (0.790) (0.815) (0.539) income bracket -0.002 -0.001 -0.003 -0.008 (0.559) (0.539) (0.439) (0.287) Occupation dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Seasonal dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes # Households 1330 1450 1336 1336 Hansen J statistic 29.145 29.067 1.616 (p-value) 0.060 0.204 Adj. R-squared -0.490 0.712 0.441 0.386 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% A description of the variables is reported in Table I. Instrument Set: second lag of local unemployment rate, the inflation rate, aggregate income growth rate, mortgage rate, household-specific debt growth rate and credit-constrained indicator. First stage Regressions Regressions Variable Column Partial R2 F test P-value RCt 0.0846 130.9 0.0000 ? Ct 0.14 230.61 0.0000 ? ct-1 (I) 0.1587 267.17 0.0000 RCt 0.0768 126.08 0.0000 ? ct-1 (II) 0.162 292.84 0.0000 RCt 0.0014 3.89 0.0086 ? Ct 0.0744 226.34 0.0000 ? ct-1 (III) 0.0814 249.38 0.0000 ? Ct 0.0744 226.34 0.0000 ? ct-1 (IV) 0.0814 249.38 0.0000 Table VIII Effect of a smaller IV set In this table I perform the same regressions as in Column I of Table VI with a progressively smaller instrument set. The instruments used in the estimation in the paper are: marginal tax rate, various lags of local unemployment rate, inflation rate, aggregate disposable income growth rate, mortgage rate, and some individual variables such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged off, automatic credit line changes, and credit constrained indicator. In Column II, I eliminate the marginal tax rate from the IV set illustrated above. In Column III I further eliminate the unemployment rate; in Column IV the inflation rate; in Column V all but one lags of aggregate income; in column VI the amount charged off; finally, in Column VII, I eliminate the credit line increases. The IV set I am left with exactly identifies the system and is composed by the first available lag of mortgage rate, aggregate income growth, household debt growth rate and credit constrained indicator. The results show that restricting the IV set doesn?t change the coefficients on ? Ct and ? ct-1, or their significance. The coefficient that is most sensitive to the shrinking of the IV set is that on the risk free interest rate, which happens sometimes to be negative, even though very close to zero and very imprecisely measured. (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) (VII) RCt -1.727*** -1.743*** -1.742*** -1.750*** -1.738*** -1.752*** -1.568*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Rft 0.448 0.408 -0.002 0.362 -0.009 -0.024 0.322 (0.537) (0.576) (0.998) (0.670) (0.992) (0.981) (0.762) ? Ct 0.258*** 0.266*** 0.370*** 0.283** 0.354** 0.352** 0.365** (0.005) (0.004) (0.001) (0.036) (0.031) (0.034) (0.029) ? ct-1 0.530*** 0.527*** 0.530*** 0.529*** 0.526*** 0.523*** 0.575*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) ? Ct-1 0.007 0.007 0.010* 0.007 0.009 0.009 0.010 (0.195) (0.202) (0.083) (0.247) (0.190) (0.215) (0.188) # of Households 2220 2220 2220 2220 2220 2220 2220 Hansen J statistic 8.725 8.292 3.322 2.286 0.819 0.816 - (p-value) 0.463 0.405 0.650 0.683 0.664 0.366 - Adj. R-squared 0.214 0.211 0.158 0.203 0.168 0.169 0.156 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Table IX External Reference Shifts measured by Lottery Winnings In Column (I) to (IV) of this Table, I reproduce the estimations in Table VI, using lottery winnings dummies instead than the city consumption. I estimate the following Euler equation: ? lnci,t=k1+? 0Lottery+? -1Lottery_lagged+?? lnci,t-1+? ln(1+(Ri,tf-1)Pr[Yi,tH]) +? ln(1+( Ri,tC 1)1[B])+? 1? agei,t+? 2? agei,t+? i,t In Column (V), I repeat the regression in Column (I), adding some additional controls about the lottery event: the fraction of winners opting for annuity payments and total winnings in the city in the given quarter. The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) RCt -1.664*** -1.854*** -1.856*** -1.867*** -1.863*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Rft 1.508*** 1.929*** 1.934*** 1.955*** 1.949*** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Lottery 0.136* 0.229** 0.228** 0.229** 0.210** (0.087) (0.025) (0.026) (0.025) (0.040) ? ct-1 0.548*** 0.537*** 0.537*** 0.538*** 0.539*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Lottery_lagged -0.093 -0.164 -0.165 -0.165 -0.156 (0.259) (0.128) (0.125) (0.124) (0.146) Age 0.004* 0.004* 0.005* 0.005* (0.070) (0.084) (0.054) (0.054) Age2 -0.000** -0.000** -0.000*** -0.000*** (0.012) (0.014) (0.009) (0.009) marital status 0.020 0.021 0.021 0.022 (0.188) (0.173) (0.167) (0.160) homeowner -0.005 -0.003 -0.004 -0.004 (0.852) (0.908) (0.896) (0.893) income bracket -0.006 -0.006 -0.006 -0.006 (0.120) (0.101) (0.122) (0.114) self_empl 0.078** 0.066* 0.066* (0.043) (0.093) (0.098) Total winnings 0.000 (0.497) Prop. annuity -0.245 (0.598) Occupation dummies Yes Yes Seasonal dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes # of Households 24066 15435 15435 15435 15435 Hansen J statistic 9.650 6.737 6.647 6.929 6.918 (p-value) 0.140 0.241 0.248 0.924 0.912 C statistic* 3.214 0.565 0.628 0.476 0.532 (p-value) 0.360 0.904 0.890 0.226 0.227 Adj. R-squared 0.270 0.268 0.268 0.267 0.267 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% + Instruments tested: lags of debt outstanding, amount charged off, change in credit line and credit constraints measure. A description of the variables is reported in Table I. Instrument set: marginal tax rate, aggregate disposable income growth rate and some individual variables such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged off, automatic credit line changes, and a credit constrained indicator. First Stage Regressions (I) (II) (III) (IV) Adj. R2 Adj. R2 Adj. R2 Adj. R2 RCt 0.0651 0.0538 0.0566 0.056 Rft 0.9537 0.9536 0.9536 0.9536 ? ct-1 0.0247 0.0220 0.0220 0.0221 p-value p-value p-value p-value RCt 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Rft 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 ? ct-1 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Table X Estimations by Occupation In this Table I reproduce the regression in Column (IV) of Table VI, separately for each of the main occupations in the data set. The purpose is to control for the stability of the internal habit coefficient across occupations. This can help address the concern that unobservable aggregate shocks that affect different HHs differently might cause the findings. The estimation equation is: ? lnci,t=k1+? 0? lnCi,t+? -1? lnCi,t-1+?? lnci,t-1+? ln(1+(Ri,tf-1)Pr[Yi,tH]) +? ln(1+( Ri,tC 1)1[B])+? 1? agei,t+? 2? agei,t+? i,t Column I estimates the model for a generic group that didn?t specify the occupation, Col. (II) for administrative and staff, Col. (III) for white collars, Col (IV) for blue collars, Col. (V) for people holding technical jobs, and Col. (VI) for self-employed. The Appendix contains a more detailed description of these occupations. The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) RCt -1.906*** -2.532** -1.379 -2.474 -1.191** -1.139 (0.002) (0.022) (0.414) (0.198) (0.037) (0.462) Rft -0.547 2.600 5.209 1.443 0.491 -6.713 (0.701) (0.341) (0.204) (0.829) (0.830) (0.371) ? Ct 0.434** 0.677 -0.100 0.121 0.302 -0.005 (0.044) (0.131) (0.822) (0.912) (0.125) (0.995) ? ct-1 0.497*** 0.546*** 0.197 0.446* 0.502*** 0.425** (0.000) (0.000) (0.318) (0.086) (0.000) (0.016) ? Ct-1 0.151 0.136 0.436 3.013 0.405*** 0.965 (0.468) (0.944) (0.871) (0.447) (0.004) (0.784) Age 0.008 0.009 0.008 -0.038 -0.017 0.023 (0.196) (0.606) (0.767) (0.370) (0.130) (0.384) Age2 -0.000* -0.000 -0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.000 (0.090) (0.530) (0.710) (0.487) (0.111) (0.273) marital status 0.016 -0.148 0.024 0.214 0.095 0.059 (0.652) (0.145) (0.864) (0.384) (0.267) (0.565) homeowner -0.079 -0.232 0.125 0.222 0.008 -0.001 (0.142) (0.250) (0.483) (0.424) (0.927) (0.996) #of Households 722 160 66 80 265 50 Hansen J statistic 2.414 3.344 6.694 4.873 3.341 2.638 (p-value) 0.660 0.502 0.375 0.301 0.638 0.942 C statistic 1.040 1.427 1.961 3.095 0.898 0.120 (p-value) 0.594 0.490 0.153 0.213 0.502 0.620 Adj. R-squared 0.156 0.259 0.175 0.169 0.121 0.243 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Table XI Robustness Checks In this Table I analyze the robustness of the results to the inclusion of various measures of economic activity to the regression: the state-level income growth rate (Col (I)), the lead of the state-level income growth rate (Col (II)), change in city-level unemployment rates (Col (III)), housing market conditions (Col. (IV)). I also check the effect of adding an extra lag of the consumption growth rate (Col. (V)), year dummies to control for aggregate shocks (Col. VI)), and the growth of household debt (Col. (VII)). The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) (VII) RCt -1.878*** -1.862*** -1.871*** -1.833*** -2.054*** -1.849*** -1.322*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.005) Rft 2.116 1.213 0.550 0.711 0.266 3.113 0.189 (0.174) (0.230) (0.527) (0.432) (0.777) (0.548) (0.835) ? Ct 0.271** 0.268** 0.442** 0.290** 0.311** 0.266** 0.295** (0.037) (0.045) (0.016) (0.030) (0.020) (0.039) (0.024) ? ct-1 0.501*** 0.507*** 0.509*** 0.503*** 0.453*** 0.508*** 0.445*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) ? Ct-1 0.014 0.012 0.021 0.014 0.016 0.013 0.014 (0.164) (0.251) (0.107) (0.184) (0.105) (0.234) (0.161) Age -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.004 -0.000 -0.000 0.004 (0.109) (0.135) (0.188) (0.324) (0.261) (0.150) (0.419) Age2 0.023 0.025 0.021 0.000 0.027 0.025 -0.000 (0.375) (0.360) (0.466) (0.138) (0.348) (0.366) (0.199) Marit_status -0.014 -0.015 -0.028 0.026 -0.039 -0.014 0.023 (0.724) (0.708) (0.498) (0.336) (0.361) (0.722) (0.401) Homeowner -0.002 -0.002 -0.003 -0.012 -0.000 -0.002 -0.025 (0.692) (0.712) (0.650) (0.767) (0.956) (0.701) (0.538) Income bracket 0.068 0.072 0.080 -0.004 0.092 0.071 -0.002 (0.262) (0.248) (0.201) (0.466) (0.158) (0.248) (0.764) Self_empl -1.878*** -1.862*** -1.871*** 0.065 -2.054*** -1.849*** 0.057 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.288) (0.000) (0.000) (0.331) Occupation dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes ? lnincome 0.020 (0.319) ? lnincome _lead 0.012 (0.434) ? ln U_rate -0.003 (0.465) Median House Value 0.000 (0.705) Rent 0.000 (0.544) (? ct)2 -0.013 (0.527) ? ct-2 0.170*** (0.000) ? lndebtt -0.157* (0.060) Year dummies Yes Seasonal dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes # Households 1432 1432 1432 1432 1432 1432 1432 Hansen J statistic 6.986 7.245 4.546 7.890 12.705 5.397 9.695 (p-value) 0.538 0.524 0.576 0.545 0.176 0.524 0.287 C statistic+ 5.224 3.204 2.892 3.933 5.665 3.204 2.487 (p-value) 0.265 0.510 0.715 0.415 0.226 0.798 0.647 Adj. R-squared 0.230 0.231 0.176 0.219 0.249 0.232 0.264 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% + Instruments tested: lags of debt outstanding, amount charged off, change in credit line and credit constraints measure. A description of the variables is reported in Table I. Instrument set: marginal tax rate, the local unemployment rate, the inflation rate, aggregate disposable income growth rate, mortgage rate, and some individual variables such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged off, automatic credit line changes, and a credit constrained indicator. Table XII Does Local Aggregate Consumption Proxy for Individual Income? In order to answer this question I use household-level data from the PSID, in which individual income is provided.1 I investigate whether local aggregate consumption provides any information about household income once aggregate income is available. The regression is the following: ? lnincomeindividual, it= ? + ? 1? lnINCOMEaggregate, it + ? 2? lnCcitylevel, it + ? 3agei+ ? 4age2i+? it Dummy variables capturing marital status, occupational choice, seasonal fluctuations and whether the individual owns the house in which he lives are included in some of the regressions as well. The null hypothesis is that once we control for aggregate income, the coefficient on aggregate consumption is small and statistically insignificant. The results below confirm this hypothesis and suggest that aggregate consumption doesn?t proxy for individual income. I have also tried the above regression using the growth rate of future HH income as the dependent variable. The results are presented in columns IV to VI and show that neither aggregate income nor consumption are good predictors of future individual income. The regression is the following: ? lnincome_leadindividual, it+1= ? + ? 1? lnINCOMEaggregate, it + ? 2? lnCaggregate, it + ? 3agei+ ? 4 age2i +? it Notice should be given to the fact that the time period analyzed is not very long, spanning from 1997 to 2001. Unfortunately a longer time series of city-level consumption is not available. Dependent Variable ? lnincomeindividual, it ? lnincome_leadindividual, it+1 (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) ? lnC 0.045 0.066 0.051 0.093 0.057 0.053 (0.550) (0.377) (0.492) (0.290) (0.474) (0.508) ? lnINCOME 2.697*** 2.660*** 2.887*** -0.674 -0.334 -0.525 (0.009) (0.009) (0.005) (0.726) (0.849) (0.768) Age -0.018** -0.023*** -0.026*** 0.001 -0.000 -0.002 (0.041) (0.010) (0.005) (0.940) (0.967) (0.886) Age2 0.000* 0.000** 0.000*** -0.000 0.000 0.000 (0.075) (0.022) (0.006) (0.989) (0.915) (0.818) Marital status -0.057 -0.076 -0.072 -0.077 -0.094 -0.112* (0.241) (0.144) (0.172) (0.243) (0.153) (0.098) Homeowner dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Occupation dummies Yes Yes Observations 921 891 891 426 413 413 R-squared 0.017 0.022 0.036 0.019 0.017 0.027 p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Sample: households in the PSID living in California. Time span: 1997 to 2001.2 Variables description and definitions: ? lnincomeindividual, it is the quarterly growth rate of household total income; ? lnINC is the quarterly growth rate of aggregate California per capita income (Source: California DOF); ? lnC is the quarterly growth rate of city- level aggregate taxable sales and constitutes my measure of aggregate consumption (Source: California DOF); Age is the age of the head of the household; Marital status is a dummy equal to 1 if the head of the HH is married and 0 otherwise; the Homeowner dummy equals 1 if the HH owns the house in which it lives and 0 otherwise; the Occupational dummies are dummies that categorize HH heads in main occupational areas and are built to be as similar as possible to those used in the rest of the paper. 1Unfortunately, this dataset doesn?t contain a good measure of consumption; for other drawbacks of the PSID see Section 3.2. 2 This is the period for which data on taxable sales are available on the California Department of Finance website. Table XIII Alternative Explanations: Liquidity Constraints and Precautionary Saving Motives This Table contains tests of the habit persistence hypothesis against the liquidity constraint and precautionary saving motive alternatives. The baseline regression to which the results are compared is: ? lnci,t=k1+? 0? lnCi,t+? -1? lnCi,t-1+?? lnci,t-1+? ln(1+(Ri,tf-1)Pr[Yi,tH]) +? ln(1+( Ri,tC -1)1[B])+? 1? agei,t+? 2? agei,t+? i,t Col. (I) and (II) re-estimate the regression on two sub-samples of unconstrained and credit constrained HHs; col (III) and (IV) perform the same regression as (I) and (II) adding the lag of income growth rate. Col (V) adds the lagged growth rate of income to the regression; Col (VI) adds a credit constrained indicator. Col (VII) adds the square of consumption growth to the regression. The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) (VII) RCt 1.788 -1.109 -0.141 -2.395 -1.879*** -0.603 -1.695*** (0.390) (0.829) (0.939) (0.638) (0.000) (0.423) (0.000) Rft -2.313 3.906 -6.201* 7.733 0.414 0.161 1.543 (0.556) (0.350) (0.099) (0.124) (0.694) (0.870) (0.287) ? Ct 0.644** 0.186 0.267 0.233 0.274** 0.240* 0.290** (0.035) (0.674) (0.392) (0.598) (0.035) (0.063) (0.024) ? ct-1 0.565*** 0.557*** 0.416*** 0.693*** 0.502*** 0.498*** 0.504*** (0.000) (0.007) (0.005) (0.002) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) ? lnincomet-1 0.081** -0.076 0.012 (0.048) (0.124) (0.473) ? Ct-1 0.023 -0.362*** 0.016 -0.396*** 0.014 0.011 0.014 (0.307) (0.005) (0.269) (0.003) (0.165) (0.253) (0.184) Age -0.015 0.001 -0.006 0.006 0.005 0.001 0.004 (0.241) (0.963) (0.596) (0.708) (0.276) (0.900) (0.339) Age2 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 (0.384) (0.968) (0.842) (0.736) (0.111) (0.775) (0.149) Marit_status 0.026 -0.048 0.009 -0.038 0.023 0.012 0.026 (0.759) (0.490) (0.902) (0.590) (0.372) (0.623) (0.372) Homeowner -0.072 -0.148 -0.021 -0.159 -0.015 0.007 -0.017 (0.529) (0.247) (0.840) (0.236) (0.713) (0.839) (0.691) Income bracket 0.015 0.027* 0.008 0.024 -0.002 0.001 -0.003 (0.437) (0.094) (0.585) (0.173) (0.698) (0.822) (0.653) Self_empl -0.188 0.243 -0.031 0.287 0.068 0.063 0.067 (0.473) (0.347) (0.885) (0.271) (0.266) (0.177) (0.296) Credit constr. indic. 0.062 (0.327) (? ct)2 -0.013 (0.527) Occupation dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Seasonal dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes # Obs 773 347 773 347 1432 1432 1432 Hansen J statistic 5.400 3.298 3.780 1.028 7.491 7.426 7.567 (p-value) 0.483 0.654 0.779 0.906 0.485 0.406 0.472 C statistic 0.493 0.000 0.079 0.002 5.174 2.911 3.540 (p-value) 0.249 0.990 0.286 0.966 0.270 0.491 0.477 Adj. R-squared 0.229 0.282 0.165 0.240 0.230 0.255 0.233 Robust p values in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% A description of the variables is reported in Table I. Instrument set: marginal tax rate, the local unemployment rate, the inflation rate, aggregate disposable income growth rate, mortgage rate, and some individual variables such as lags of the growth rate of debt, amount charged off, automatic credit line changes, and a credit constrained indicator. Table XIV Aggregate Consumption Regressions This Table investigates the aggregate implications of household level consumption choices. Columns (I), (II), and (III) present the results of estimating an aggregate Euler equation based on per capita consumption: (a) ? ln? ci,t= ? +? ? ln? ci,t-1 + Rft + ? t. Columns (IV), (V), and (VI) presents the results of estimating the same Euler equation using correctly aggregated data: (b) ?? lnci,t= ? +? ?? lnci,t-1 + Rft + ? t. Finally, Columns (VII), (VIII), and (IX) illustrate the effect of adding moments of the cross sectional distribution of consumption growth rates to regression. The standard errors are corrected for the non-independence of the observations within the same household. In addition, controls for the evolution of city-level prices and seasonal dummies are included in all the regressions. Per-capita Consumption Aggregation Method Correct Aggregation Method Per-capita Consumption Aggregation Method plus Moments Dependent variable ? ln? ct ?? lnct ? ln? ct (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) (VII) (VIII) (IX) Rft 1.361 1.468 0.872 -0.112 -0.018 -0.042 2.401* 1.454** 1.444** (0.186) (0.144) (0.190) (0.818) (0.974) (0.926) (0.064) (0.038) (0.040) ? ln? ci,t-1 -0.685 -0.739 -0.494 0.139 -0.791** 0.233 (0.205) (0.191) (0.164) (0.942) (0.033) (0.704) ?? lnci,t-1 0.515** 0.727** 0.538* (0.042) (0.039) (0.089) ? lnincomet 0.002 -0.131 (0.996) (0.404) ? lnincomet-1 0.471* 0.147 (0.061) (0.344) ? stddev/2 36.669 (0.489) ? skewness/6 2.278 (0.571) ? kurtosis/24 -4.954 (0.116) Time dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes # Obs 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 Hansen J statistic 2.244 2.061 4.108 2.286 1.213 1.210 0.002 3.532 0.370 (p-value) 0.326 0.151 0.043 0.319 0.271 0.271 0.965 0.060 0.543 Adj. R-squared 0.380 0.363 0.685 0.285 0.009 0.170 -.241 0.479 0.174 Robust * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% A description of the variables is reported in Table I. ? stddev, ? skewness, and ? kurtosis are the standard deviation, skewness and kurtosis of the cross sectional distribution of consumption. Instrument set: second lag of aggregated city-level sales, income growth rate, average mortgage rate, and unemployment rate.